Forum Home Page [see Broadridge note below]

 The Shareholder ForumTM`

Fair Investor Access

This public program was initiated in collaboration with The Conference Board Task Force on Corporate/Investor Engagement and with Thomson Reuters support of communication technologies. The Forum is providing continuing reports of the issues that concern this program's participants, as summarized  in the January 5, 2015 Forum Report of Conclusions.

"Fair Access" Home Page

"Fair Access" Program Reference

 

Related Projects 2012-2019

For graphed analyses of company and related industry returns, see

Returns on Corporate Capital

See also analyses of

Shareholder Support Rankings

 
 
 

Forum reference:

Scholar discovers activist campaigns depend on shareholder communication

 

For the full paper summarized below by its authors, see

In the following video, the author presents his paper in a December 2017 lecture at an event held at Bar-Ilan University:

 

 

Source: The Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation, December 19, 2018 posting

Soft Shareholder Activism

Posted by Doron Levit (University of Pennsylvania), on Wednesday, December 19, 2018

Editor’s Note: Doron Levit is Assistant Professor of Finance at The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. This post is based on a recent article by Professor Levit, forthcoming in the Review of Financial Studies. Related research from the Program on Corporate Governance includes Dancing with Activists by Lucian Bebchuk, Alon Brav, Wei Jiang, and Thomas Keusch (discussed on the Forum here).

The modus operandi of a typical activist investor is to target a public company and propose major changes to its strategy, financial policy, operations, and personal. To defend themselves against these proposals, companies use poison pills, staggered boards, dual-class structures, and other measures. Securities regulation and disclosure requirements also limit the power of activists. In practice, activists rarely own a controlling stake. Without control, activist investors cannot force their ideas on their target companies; they must persuade its board of directors or the majority of shareholders that adopting their proposals is in the best interests of the firm. Simply put, shareholder activism requires communication and persuasion.

Consistent with this idea, recent evidence suggests that behind-the-scenes communications between investors and firms is an important corporate governance mechanism, perhaps more important than previously thought (e.g., McCahery et al. 2016). This evidence raises two fundamental questions that have been overlooked by the existing literature. First, what factors contribute to successful dialogues between investors and firms? Second, under what circumstances will investors resort to more aggressive tactics, and when will they choose to exit?

My article Soft Shareholder Activism, which is forthcoming in the Review of Financial Studies, investigates the conditions under which communications between investors and firms is an effective form of shareholder activism. I develop a model in which the activist can communicate (cheap-talk) with the board of the target company, and depending on the reaction to her demand, the activist can either launch a public campaign (i.e., employing a “voice” mechanism) or exit her position. The innovation of the model is the introduction of the possibility of direct communications between investors and firms into a framework with voice and exit, the “traditional” governance mechanisms. Moreover, different from the existing literature, the activist in my model cannot force her ideas on the company; she must either persuade the board to adopt her proposal, or persuade other shareholders to support her campaign. My model emphasizes this important but often neglected aspect of shareholder activism, and as such, offers a new perspective to this important literature.

The challenge of the activist in this model is to convince the board, who is biased and uninformed, to change the status quo of the firm (e.g., spinning off a division). At equilibrium, the board accommodates the activist’s demand either because it is persuaded by her arguments that changing the status quo is in the best interests of the firm or out of fear that the activist will launch a successful public campaign if her demand is ignored. Communication is effective if the activist can use her private information to influence the board’s decision at equilibrium.

My analysis demonstrates that the threat of voice facilitates communication since the most effective way directors can avoid the adverse consequences of a public campaign is by accommodating the activist’s demand. In turn, the expected accommodation of the board increases the incentive of the activist to engage and communicate in the first place. Generally, an activist’s threat is more credible when rallying support from other shareholders is easier (e.g., shareholder base is undispersed), control is contestable (e.g., declassified board, one class of shares, no supermajority provisions), or the reputational and monetary damage to the incumbent directors from a successful campaign is severe. The model predicts that these factors would contribute to more effective communications. Moreover, the analysis suggests that a public campaign is a sign of ineffective behind-the-scenes communications, and vice a versa. Importantly, it implies that factors that predict high frequency of public campaigns would in fact suggest that the employed tactics are not effective enough to induce boards to comply with demands that activists make behind closed-doors. Without explicitly accounting for the possibility of unobserved communications, an empiricist might reach the wrong conclusions.

The effect of exit on communication is more nuanced. On one hand, the temptation of an activist to “cut and run” harms the credibility of her threat to launch a public campaign if her demand is ignored. Therefore, exit has an indirect effect on communication, through its negative effect on voice. On the other hand, the option to exit increases the activist’s credibility through two related but novel channels. First, with exit, the activist insists on changing the status quo only if the benefit from doing so is also higher than what she expects to get from selling her shares. As a result, the board is convinced that whenever the activist demands a change, the benefit to shareholders must be very high. This effect relaxes the tension between the activist and the board and thereby facilitates communication. Second, exit can also increase the credibility of the activist’s threat to launch a successful public campaign. Essentially, the option to exit gives the activist an opportunity to “put her money where her mouth is” by choosing not to exercise this option. Therefore, the activist has more credibility vis-a-vis shareholders and the board, and communication is more effective in equilibrium. These results highlight that exit can complement voice and facilitate communication.

The analysis shows that the trade-off between these opposing forces and the overall effect of exit on communication is determined by the properties of the activist’s proposal and the voice mechanism, which leads to novel empirical predictions on the factors that contribute to successful dialogues between investors and firms. Specifically, if voice is ineffective as a governance mechanism (e.g., the target company has a dual class share, a controlling shareholder, or a staggered board and draconian supermajority provisions) or if the activist’s proposal is risky relative to the status quo (e.g., the target operates in an emerging industry and the proposal is not a standard fix to its balance sheet or corporate governance), the cut and run effect is dominated and exit facilitates communication. However, if voice is effective and the activist’s proposal is relatively safe, the cut and run effect dominates and exit hinders communication. In general, the effect of exit is more pronounced when the stock is liquid, the short-term capital gains taxes are low, anonymous trade is feasible, or adverse selection is mild. The model predicts that these various factors will be associated with the frequency of successful dialogues between investors and firms.

As a whole, my analysis highlights the importance of communications between investors and firms as a form of shareholder activism.

The complete article is available here.

 

Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation
All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by their respective owners. Other content © 2018 The President and Fellows of Harvard College.

 

 

This Forum program was open, free of charge, to anyone concerned with investor interests in the development of marketplace standards for expanded access to information for securities valuation and shareholder voting decisions. As stated in the posted Conditions of Participation, the purpose of this public Forum's program was to provide decision-makers with access to information and a free exchange of views on the issues presented in the program's Forum Summary. Each participant was expected to make independent use of information obtained through the Forum, subject to the privacy rights of other participants.  It is a Forum rule that participants will not be identified or quoted without their explicit permission.

This Forum program was initiated in 2012 in collaboration with The Conference Board and with Thomson Reuters support of communication technologies to address issues and objectives defined by participants in the 2010 "E-Meetings" program relevant to broad public interests in marketplace practices. The website is being maintained to provide continuing reports of the issues addressed in the program, as summarized in the January 5, 2015 Forum Report of Conclusions.

Inquiries about this Forum program and requests to be included in its distribution list may be addressed to access@shareholderforum.com.

The information provided to Forum participants is intended for their private reference, and permission has not been granted for the republishing of any copyrighted material. The material presented on this web site is the responsibility of Gary Lutin, as chairman of the Shareholder Forum.

Shareholder Forum™ is a trademark owned by The Shareholder Forum, Inc., for the programs conducted since 1999 to support investor access to decision-making information. It should be noted that we have no responsibility for the services that Broadridge Financial Solutions, Inc., introduced for review in the Forum's 2010 "E-Meetings" program and has since been offering with the “Shareholder Forum” name, and we have asked Broadridge to use a different name that does not suggest our support or endorsement.